CHAPTER 2
THE ASSAULT ON LABOR
To hundreds of millions of workers
around the world, the picture is familiar:
wages are dropping, good jobs are disappearing, services are
deteriorating, plants are closing. A global assault on workers' living standards
is taking place. But who and what is behind this assault? and how is it being
carried out?
At the most elementary level, it's
true to say that the assault in being planned and carried out by world
capitalists, by a global capitalist class.
In itself, such a bald statement says very little. Who is the capitalist class and through what
actual institutions are they carrying out the policies of austerity,
restructuring and privatization? For
while capitalists and capitalism have dominated the world economy for three
centuries, how this domination is exercised has changed repeatedly and
radically, even in the past couple of generations. So, to begin to understand the assault that labor faces and has
begun to respond to, a good place to start is to look at labor's adversary --
the institutions of capitalist rule.
Today, these institutions are
characterized above all by an unprecedented degree of concentration and global
unity. The "global economy" that is so much talked about in the
financial pages means that now in every country in the world it is the same
massive multinational corporations, the same international organizations, the
same International Monetary Fund that
are calling the shots, that are
dictating economic policy. The
rivalries among capitalist units are subordinated through these multinational
institutions into a single unified and global class, headquartered in the
United States. This is true at the
level of corporations and the individual capitalists that control them, at the
level of national governments and at the level of intergovernmental
institutions. For the first time in
human history, since the 1991 collapse of the Soviet Union, the entire planet
is joined in a single political and economic empire. This is true not through some clandestine conspiracy, but through
the open control exercised by the International Monetary Fund, by the giant
corporations and by the unrivaled economic political and military power of the
United States.
This global unity is a source of
enormous strength to the capitalist class, but it also is a source of potential
political weakness. For today,
throughout the world, workers for the first time are confronting not a myriad
of separate enemies, but a single enemy.
In demonstrations round the world, the IMF is now the most prominent
organization denounced, not the local national government. And the growing awareness of a single enemy
can, and in certain ways is, leading to a growing awareness of the need for a
similar global unity on the part of labor.
GLOBAL CORPORATIONS
The basic unit of a capitalist
economy is the corporation, and today the world economy is dominated by a
relatively small number of giant multinational companies. In the United States, the 500 largest
corporations have revenues, in 1994, equal to no less than 92% of the national
income, excluding that portion provided by governmental services. On a world
scale, the largest one thousand corporations had revenues of 8 trillion dollars
a year, equal to a third of the total global income.[1] The myriad smaller companies supply the
needs and dance to the tune of these global behemoths.
Who owns and controls these thousand
companies? Who are the capitalists
themselves? Corporations are directly
controlled by their boards of directors, which typically number about a dozen
directors per board. But these thousand
companies aren't run by 12,000 people, since typically the average individual
capitalist sits on the boards of five or six major corporations. Only about 2,500 individuals constitute the
board members of these thousand giants.
All of them meet together repeatedly on the several boards they sit on,
so the interest of the corporations and of the class as a whole are
continuously being discussed. In
particular, nearly all these individuals sit on the boards of some one or two
hundred top financial institutions, where the broader concerns of the
capitalist markets are among the topics routinely considered at board meetings,
for they bear directly on the health of these financial institutions -- banks,
insurance companies, and investment companies.
For example, on the board of the
Bankers Trust New York Company, one of the world's leading bank holding
companies, sit directors of Mobil, J.C. Penney, Exxon, Warner Lambert, American
Express, Corning, Revlon, RJR Nabisco, Sara Lee, Union Carbide, and Xerox,
among others.[2] In a 1980 survey by the staff of the US
Senate Committee on Government Affairs, Bankers Trust directors sat on the
board of no less than 74 major corporations ranging from industrial giants like
IBM, insurance companies like Mutual of New York, media like the New York Times
and Macmillan Inc.[3] Such interlocking boards provide control
over institutions, such as mutual life insurance companies, that are not
formally owned by shareholders.
Equally, they provide meeting places for directors of ostensibly
competing firms to coordinate policies.
Thus today directors from Exxon and Mobil both sit on the board of
Bankers Trust. In 1980, on the same
board sat directors from Ford and General Motors. And, of course, directors from various competing financial
institutions sit together on many boards of industrial firms -- First Chicago
and Chase Manhattan on General Motors board, Chase and Bankers Trust on the
boards of JC Penney and Xerox and so on.[4] Again, in 1980 directors for J.P. Morgan sat
on no less than 35 corporate boards with directors from Citicorp, nine with
directors from Bankers Trust, 23 with those from Manufacturers Hanover.[5]
The sharp edge of "free market
competition" is somewhat blunted within the chummy network of these
directors. But, of course, boards of
directors are responsible to the shareholders of corporations, the owners. Who owns these thousand global
companies? The first answer is ...
other companies, specifically financial institutions : pension funds, life
insurance companies, mutual funds, investment companies, bank holding
companies, trust departments. In the
US, 46% of all stock in all corporations is owned by financial institutions.[6] But among the top 500 corporations, the
concentration of institutional ownerships is considerably greater. As shown in the accompanying chart, the
overwhelming majority of major US corporations are more than 50% owned by
financial institutions and virtually none has less than 40% institutional
ownership. So while free market
publicists write that US industry is owned by millions of shareholders, in
fact, the giants like GE, GM, Ford, Mobil, Exxon, IBM and so on are all either
majority or near-majority owned by financial institutions.
So who really owns the
corporations? In terms of who controls
the shares and votes them, who influences the policies of the companies as
major shareholders, the answer is less than 100 institutions, a combination of
bank trust funds, investment companies, insurance companies, and a few public
pension funds. The individuals
(overwhelmingly men) who represent these firms on the boards of the top 500
corporations are representing the interests of the major shareholders -- they
are both directors and, in effect, owners, for ultimately it is the boards of
these financial institutions that make policy to be carried out in the
companies where they are major shareholders.
This power of ownership is reinforced by the fact that the same
institutions, especially the banks and insurance companies, are, of course, the
creditors of the major corporations as well, holding over two-thirds of all
corporate debt.[7]
Well then, if the financial
institutions own the corporations, who owns the financial institutions? The financial institutions own other
financial institutions, as shown in Chart 2.
The majority of shares of virtually all the top banks are held by other
financial institutions, and in most cases, ownership is concentrated in between
two dozen and four dozen institutions.
Thus Wells Fargo is majority owned by some 30 institutions, and Citicorp
by 55,(mainly the same ones). [8]
The shareholders, those to whom the boards of directors are responsible, turn
out to be...themselves. The same
individuals who sit on the boards of the giant financial institutions,
collectively sit on the boards of the institutions that own all these
corporations, including the financial ones.
The 2,500 people we mentioned above are the same 2,500 who constitute the boards of these top financial
institutions. It is they , not the
millions of small shareholders, who exercise ownership and control over the
world's largest corporations and over the world economy--a huge concentration
of power in the hands of individuals responsible to no one but each other.
The picture is a bit more
complicated, however, since in many cases these institutions are holding stock
to benefit other institutions -- principally the private pension funds. Five
banks in particular, in the US, (Mellon, State Street, Northern Trust, Bankers
Trust and Chase Manhattan) manage assets for 82% of pension funds.[9] In terms of ultimate, or beneficial
ownership -- who gets the money, rather than who controls the shares -- private
pension funds are the largest players, with half of all institutional holdings,
followed by mutual funds, with a quarter, public pensions 18% and life
insurance companies 7%.[10] In general, the pension funds allocate their
control to other institutions, but they, in turn, are controlled by the boards
of the major corporations. Pension funds, too, are highly concentrated, with
over 50% of total assets in the hands of the top 100 pension funds.[11] So again, ownership runs in a circle, coming
back to the same 2,500 people.
Ironically, in legal terms, the
pension fund assets that are needed to cover their obligations (more than 98%
of all assets) are the property of the pension holders -- mainly their workers
-- and are merely held in trust by the corporations' funds. Yet not only do the pension funds provide
the means by which corporate boards of directors can exert ownership control
over other large corporations, they have a huge impact on corporate profits as
well. Since corporations need
contribute only so much to pension funds as are not covered by the earnings of
pension fund assets --stocks and bonds -- the more the pension funds earn, the
less the corporations contribute and in direct proportion the greater the
corporate profits. In 1992, for example,
pre-tax corporate profits were 370 billion dollars, while private pension fund
assets held by corporations were 3.1 trillion. [12]Thus
a 1% increase in the value of fund assets that year would tend to increase
profits by 8%. Again, the big
corporations are linked together into a web of control and profit, where the
success of one depends on the causes of all others. "Free market competition" has gone the way of the Dodo
some decades back.
This close interconnection extends
across international borders, despite the loud propaganda about "international
competition". In the first place,
many of the individual corporations are themselves completely multinational,
having their production facilities spread around the globe. In the second, the web of interconnections
among corporations respects no artificial boundaries. In a 1987 study of the auto industry[13],
for example, Prof. Cheitran Marfels found that 29% of GM autos, 48% of Fords',
31% of Chrysler's, and 39% of Renault's were made outside the "home"
country. Among the 17 firms that make
nearly all the world's cars, interrelationships were the rule. General Motors owned 34% of Isuzu, 50% of
Korean automaker Daewoo, 5% of Suzuki and had joint ventures with Toyota and
Volvo. Ford owned 25% of Mazda and had
joint ventures with Volkswagen. Chrysler
owned 24% of Mitsubishi, which, in turn, owned 15% of Hyundai, and Chrysler as
well owned 15% of Peugeot. As the chart
shows, every one of the leading manufacturers was linked directly or indirectly
with every other through mutual ownership or joint ventures. In many cases the
"foreign imports" auto makers point to with trembling fingers
(generally to try to justify their latest attacks on wages or working
conditions) come from plants wholly or partially owned by the companies doing
the pointing. Of course, companies try to maximize their own sales -- but not
at the cost of seriously damaging rivals in whom they generally have
significant investments. International
competition exists more as a useful
myth than an economic reality.
Thus we see that control over the
world's giant corporations and over the
world economy is concentrated in an extremely tiny ruling layer of big
capitalists, probably numbering no more than two to three thousand people who
sit on the boards of these corporations, and exercise ownership control through
the giant financial institutions.
Naturally, these capitalists personally profit enormously from their
control over global wealth. Through
their corporations, they control at least 30 trillion of the total 40 trillion
in world financial assets.[14] But their personal wealth is immense as
well. Based on surveys of wealthiest
individuals[15],
we can estimate that the personal holdings of this tiny ruling elite totals
around 2 trillion dollars, or about one eighth of all net assets held by all
the world's households. Not only do
they make the policy decisions that govern world capitals, they derive the
lion's share of the benefits as well.
Of course, ranged around this small
elite of decision makers is a much larger capitalist class in the economic
sense -- those who derive most or all their income from investing capital. This
broader capitalist class benefits from the policies decided by the corporate
elite, but generally doesn't participate in making policy. In comparison with the population as a
whole, it is still small. In the United
States, for example, nearly half of all financial assets owned by households
are owned by the richest half percent of households, some half-million families. These capitalist families, earning at least
$200,000 a year, and on average much more, had, in 1989, 11% of the total
income of all Americans.[16] On a global scale, this broader layer of
small and medium capitalists numbers perhaps one to two million out of the
world's more than a billion families.
While workers often look on all
employers as "bosses" there is an important distinction that must be
made. Capitalists -- those whose main income is based on accumulating and
investing capital -- are a small minority even among employers, most of whom
are small employers who do not accumulate capital. In the United States, for example, there are some 11 million
small businesses, many of whom do not employ any labor other than that of the
proprietor. Those who are
self-employed are economically part of
the working class, generally gaining their living through contract work for
corporations or government. Small
employers who are not capitalists constitute an intermediate layer between
labor and capital. On the one hand,
their businesses, which tend to be services, generally prosper in proportion to
the well-being of the workers who are their main customers. On the other hand, as employers, they try to
keep their own workers' wages as low as possible. But since they generally only earn enough to cover their own
living expenses, not to accumulate and invest enough capital to constitute
their main income, they are not part of the capitalist class and their
interests are in generally sharply different from that of the capitalists. Small farmers in all countries are typical
of this intermediate layer, as are shopkeepers.
NATIONAL GOVERNMENTS
Above the level of the individual
multinational corporations and their cartels lie the various national
governments, which in many ways, are scarcely less controlled by capital than
the corporations themselves. In the
dominant capitalist nations, the so-called group of seven (the US, Canada,
Japan, Germany, The United Kingdom, France and Italy) capitalists control over
national government policies is exercised through two distinct institutional
paths. The most direct control is
through the central banks, which are virtually independent from any political
force outside the capitalist class.
More indirect, but still highly effective control is exercised by the overwhelming
power of corporate money in the electoral process.
The most powerful of the central
banks and the model for all of them is, of course, the Federal Reserve Bank of
the United States. The Bank's influence
over both the US and the world economy is direct and extremely important. The Fed is the only entity in the United
States that is empowered to create money, and it also sets the cost of that
money -- the interest rates. It can
create new money in a couple of ways: first, by simply lending money to the
Federal government, which it can do without limit. Since the Bank has no need to borrow the money that it lends, it
is simply generating the money by governmental fiat. In addition, the Fed lends, on demand, to private commercial
banks, providing them guaranteed access to money at the discount rate, the
interest rate it charges. Again, this
is new money that the Bank did not borrow from anyone and which is not
generated by taxation. Finally, it directly limits how much money commercial
banks can lend, since it sets a reserve requirement that determines the ratio
of a bank's assets that must be deposited on reserve at the Bank. Lifting these requirements reduces the
amount of money banks can lend, reducing them increases this amount, again
controlling the supply of money.
The Fed fixes the price of money --
the interest rates --as well. It does
this directly by determining the discount rate, the cost of money to the
banks. But it also sets the short term
interest rates the Federal government must pay, and short term rates generally,
by the operations of its Open Market Committee. The committee determines how much money the Fed will lend at any
time to the Federal government. Lending
more money naturally bids down interest rates, lending less increases them.
Through its control over interest
rates, the Fed, like other central banks, has a huge impact on the economy as a
whole. Increased costs of borrowing
money, in an economy heavily burdened by debt as today's is, means less money
available for expansion of production, and less money for payment of
wages. Since consumer interest rates
are pegged to commercial ones, rising interest rates also acts as an indirect
tax on workers as a whole, siphoning money out of their pockets in the form of
higher mortgage payments, car payments and credit card payments. Reduced business and consumer spending, in
turn, slows production and drops employment, as well as putting more pressure
on corporations to cut costs -- through wage cuts, benefits cuts, layoffs and
speed up. Increased unemployment caused
by production slowdowns, in turn, decreases the ability of unions to
successfully strike, and reduces their effectiveness in fighting wage cuts.
Given this vast governmental power,
it would seem that the Federal Reserve Bank, of all governmental institutions,
would have to be subject to democratic control. In fact, it is the part of government most directly controlled by
private capital. The Federal Reserve is
composed of 12 regional reserve banks, each having its own board of
directors. The boards of directors of
these Banks are "democratically" elected -- by the member commercial
banks of each region. The private banks
thus have complete control over their regional Reserve banks and their elected
directors, in turn, appoint the President and Vice President of these
banks. At a national level, the Federal
Reserve has a board of directors which are appointed by the President of the
United States. On the one hand,
however, these are not appointments as in the executive branch, serving at the
"pleasure of the President," they are appointments for 14-year terms,
and the governors cannot be removed during that term. This effectively insulates them from both the elected executive
and Congress. In addition, the most important decisions are made not by the
Board of Governors alone, but by them and the representatives of the regional
banks, responsible directly to the private bankers. Changes in the discount rates must be made by the regional bank
heads, acting with the approval of the Board of Governors. The Open Market Committee consists of the
seven governors, plus five representatives of the regional banks, so again
nearly half the power is allocated to those responsible purely to private
interests. In practice, the governors
as well respond equally to the wishes of the private banks, having no
countervailing political pressures on them.
The behavior of the Fed offers
abundant evidence that it carries out the policies of the private banks even
when that is clearly contrary to the interests of the general population. One recent example has been the openly
avowed Fed goal of preventing real wage increases, despite the fact that this
is precisely the best indicator of the general standard of living. The Fed, in the early and mid nineties, as
it raised interest rates explicitly stated that its goal was to ensure that
unemployment did not drop so far as to "increase wage
pressures". In other words,
unemployment must be maintained at a sufficiently high level that unions will
be too weak to fight for higher real wages.
A second example is the
collaboration between the Fed and the Treasury Department to funnel government
money to the commercial banks. If the
goal of these two agencies was to minimize the Federal deficit, as they often
loudly proclaimed, they would naturally want to reduce the interest payments on
the national debt. When the Fed lowered
short term rates, the Treasury could have reduced its interest payments by
shifting Federal borrowing to shorter terms.
In fact, it shifted to longer terms, which kept long-term interest rates
high because of the huge Federal demand.
At the same time, the Fed was liberally lending to banks at the discount
rate which at times fell to as low as three percent. One arm of the Federal government, the Fed was thus lending money
to private banks at 3% while another arm, the Treasury, was borrowing the same
money back from private banks at 8%.
The result was a huge direct subsidy to the banks of hundreds of
billions of dollars, paid for by US taxpayers.
While we are taking the US Federal
Reserve Bank as an example, the structure and behavior of the central banks of
Germany, England, Japan and other leading industrial nations are extremely
similar. In all cases, their main
instrument of control is their ability to fix interest rates, an instrument
which has strengthened as the debt burden of the economy has grown. The central banks use high interest rates to
apply pressure on corporations to curb working class incomes and to increase
unemployment, weakening union strength, as they did through most of the
eighties and again in the mid nineties. The banks lower rates typically to
prevent an uncontrolled deflation and credit crisis, as in the early nineties,
or to allow corporations to yield concessions to the working class, when this
is deemed politically essential, as happened in the late sixties and during the
seventies.
The central governments of the main
industrial powers are a second avenue of capitalist control over economic
policy, and a second main institution in imposing the current policies of
"structural adjustment". The
control wielded by major corporations and individual capitalists over the
national governments of the advanced countries is too widely acknowledged and
too overwhelmingly documented to require much comment here. In the United States, for example, the
overwhelming majority of funds raised by candidates of both republican and
democratic parties, and by the parties themselves, is contributed by either
corporate Political Action Committees directly, or by wealthy capitalists. The hundreds of millions of dollars in
"soft money" raised by the political parties, without any real
restrictions, is completely dominated by corporate contributions. These ties of corporations to the major
parties of Japan and Europe are scarcely less subtle.
In the advanced capitalist
countries, the national governments have played the leading role in the assault
against the working class. As we'll
detail later in this chapter, the national governments have been central in
weakening the ability of unions to resist austerity, in directly lowering wages
through cuts in their real minimum wage, in privatizing services and
industries, and in cutting essential services, such as health and education
that form part of the working class's standard of living. In general, without the leadership of the
national governments, the multinational corporations would have been totally
unable to launch a general offensive against workers.
By contrast, the national
governments of the Third World countries have been massively weakened over the
past fifteen years, ceding much of their sovereignty to international
organizations, particularly to the IMF.
The growing indebtedness of most Third World countries has led to their
national governments becoming, to a large extent, the mere enforcers of
politics that are actually formulated by the IMF and the international
financial community. These
international organizations constitute the third main institutions leading the
assault on labor.
CAPITAL'S WORLD GOVERNMENT -- THE IMF
The International Monetary Fund has
become world capital's most important economic institution and quite possibly
the most popular target of demonstrations and protests in the world. It started functioning in 1947, in the
aftermath of World War II, at a time when the United States was completely
dominant among the capitalist countries, being the only one not to have been
damaged by the war. The current
structure of the IMF preserves that American dominance to a large degree. The IMF is run by a board of governors,
appointed by the central banks of the members' countries. Voting rights, however, are proportional to
the size of the countries' economy. The
US alone has 20% of the voting rights, while the group of seven countries
together have 45%.[17] In practice, the IMF never takes action that
conflicts with the interests of American and international capital.
The IMF exerts its influence over
the world economic policies in two ways.
One method is "consultative", in that the IMF Executive
Committee meets with the governments of each member country annually and gives
it advice on economic affairs. But by
far the most important method is through its "conditional"
loans. When a country is unable to
borrow money from commercial banks and other private sources -- such as by
floating bonds -- the IMF steps in as a "lender of last resort". But there is a catch to this generosity. The loans are conditional on the country
agreeing to and carrying out a Structural Adjustment Plan (SAP) negotiated with
the IMF, and in most cases effectively dictated by the IMF. The importance of such IMF agreements is
magnified by the fact that commercial lenders will generally not resume their
own lending to a country unless it has first made an agreement with the IMF.
The international debt crises of the
early 1980's enormously increased the power of the IMF. During the seventies, Third World countries
had borrowed heavily to finance their oil imports after the 1974 oil price
increase. The further price increases in 1979, combined with soaring interest
rates and dropping commodity prices, made it impossible for many of these
countries to continue to repay their debts without further borrowing. At this point the IMF became the economic
dictator of most of the world, stepping in to impose its SAPs on dozens of
nations.
Debt was turned, via the IMF, into
an instrument of economic control. With
relatively small amounts of investment, international capital could control
vast flows of real wealth. For example,
among Third World countries the total external debt represents about 40% of
gross national product. Interest on this
debt, the only money directly controlled by the debt holders, amounts to only
2% of GNP and total debt service, payments of interest and principal, only 4%. [18]
But through the IMF's SAPs, control over the entire 4 trillion dollar Third
World GNP is given to the creditor banks.
And, of course, the IMF's own loans are only small fractions of total
debt. With 40 billion dollars in total
loans outstanding, the IMF effectively controls the Third World economy, whose
annual output is 100 times larger than this debt.
In some individual countries the situation is even more
extreme. Russia, for example, with a
$700 billion economy, is tailoring its internal economic policies according to
the IMF dictates. Yet the total
external debt of Russia is only $80 billion, 12% of GNP and the IMF loans so eagerly
sought by the Russian government amount to a few billion dollars. By contrast, the United States' foreign debt
is over one trillion dollars, and represents some 20% of GNP, yet the IMF
obviously plays no major role in dictating US economic policies. [19]
Indeed, in some cases, like Russia, the national government willingly
collaborates with the IMF to conveniently shift blame for its policies to the
Fund.
In general, however, it is the Fund
that calls the tune. And it is the tune that we have already heard --
austerity, privatization and restructuring.
The IMF universally calls for cuts in consumption, social services and
wages in all countries. In the deficit
countries, where it has the most power, it justifies these universal policies
by saying that these countries are "living beyond their means" as the
IMF's 1993 pamphlet (Common
Misconceptions About the IMF) puts it, and must cut back consumption to cut
imports and increase exports. This
prescription ignores, on the one hand, the impossibility to all countries
simultaneously decreasing imports and increasing exports. On the other hand, it ignores the historical
experience that developing countries are always net importers of capital --
indeed the United States, for most of its history, was a permanent deficit
country, and of course, is again today.
But the IMF's prescription of
austerity is not limited to developing countries, nor to those with balance of
payment deficits -- countries importing more than they export. In Italy, the IMF recommends "tighter
limits on health spending, cuts in government expenditures and wage costs"
and cuts in pensions[20]
(1994 World Outlook and Annual Report). In Germany it recommends cutting
"excessive social spending" and reductions in wages.[21] In France it recommends cutting the minimum
wage, especially for youth. [22]
(An effort which was beaten back by a massive protest of students and workers,
as we'll see in Chapter 7). In general,
it praises countries for "their efforts to reduce the bargaining power of
unions." [23]
And the IMF repeatedly blames high wages for high unemployment, on the
reasoning that if workers would only reduce the wages they accept, employers
would gladly hire all of them, a peculiar logic that ignores the fact that
decreased wages means decreased consumption and production and thus increased, not decreased, unemployment.[24]
The IMF's championing of
privatization is scarcely less subtle.
IMF's Executive Director urged governments, in an address of the IMF
board of governors, to "focus on those areas where (government's) actions
are indispensable and most effective -- security, education, health, social
safety nets and establishing transparent rules so markets can operate
efficiently -- rather than participating directly in production and
distribution of goods." [25]
In virtually every country where it operates it has either encouraged, or
enforced via conditional loans the massive sell-off of state-owned industries
to private investors, often at a fraction of the companies' real values.
On restructuring of industries --
the deliberate closing of factories to support prices -- the IMF is a bit more
reticent. It is, after all, hard to
justify the large scale destruction of productive resources. However, the IMF has expressed, for example
in its 1994 report, concern about falling prices for non oil commodities, which
it blames on oversupply. This is a bit
ironic, since, of course, the IMF's diligent efforts to cut consumption does
tend to produce downwards pressure of prices.
But, in fact, the reduction of capacity as consumption falls is a vital
part of the IMF's strategy -- without such reduction, falls in consumption
would lead to a run away deflation, as in the
Depression, and massive defaults on debts.
The most egregious examples of the
IMF policies of restructuring come as by-products of mass privatizations, where
privatized industries are generally shut down soon after they are sold
off. In Eastern Europe and the former
Soviet Union this mass shut down of industries following privatizations has led
to huge falls in production, generally by 50% or more. Similarly the large scale privatizations of
Mexican industries was followed by falls in domestic production. These restructurings occur in many cases
where the motivation is clearly to support world price structures, even at the
expense of worsening balance of payments for individual countries. For example, the IMF has forced Bangladesh,
one of the world's poorest countries, to privatize and shut down much of the
jute industry, despite the fact that jute is the country's only principle
export.[26] This seems paradoxical since the IMF
generally encourages export industries.
However, jute directly competes with synthetic fibers produced by
multinational forms whose prices have been under increasing pressure. Eliminating jute production by decreasing
overall supply acts to support fiber prices, and thus chemical company
profits. The consequent mass
unemployment and misery for hundreds of thousands of Bengali workers is, to the
IMF, a mere by-product.
IMPLEMENTING CAPITAL'S ASSAULT: AUSTERITY
The multinational corporations,
national governments and the IMF work together to impose the basic polices of
the capitalist assault: austerity, privatization and restructuring. How are these policies actually being
implemented? To begin with austerity:
the goal here is cutting the overall cost of labor, not just wages alone but
also the essential services needed to support the working population, such as
health and education.
The most important method of
imposing austerity is the global leveling downwards of wages, the setting up of
a global competition among workers that continuously eats away at labor
compensation. This involves attacking
the wages of the lowest paid workers, both locally and in the world, and then
removing all the barriers that prevent leveling wages downwards toward that
lowest level, anything that interferes with workers' competition with each
other. By analogy, capital's strategy
is like pulling the plug on a sink and watching the water drain to the lowest
available level. The wages of the
lowest paid workers are continuously reduced -- going down the drain -- and the
wages of everyone else is pulled down towards the ever-descending level of the
bottom. This occurs both as work is
shifted from high wage sectors and regions to low wage ones and as the wages of
every sector and region are pulled down through global competition. The process works both globally between
countries and within individual countries.
The techniques of carrying out this
global wage drain vary, however. For
the lowest paid sectors in the globe, competition with still lower paid workers
obviously is not an available weapon.
To pull the plug and depress the wages of these lowest paid workers, the
principal tool world-wide is the devaluation of currencies and deliberately
induced massive inflation, combined with a repressive apparatus that prevents
wages from rising in step with inflation.
For example, in 1994, the IMF and the French government enforced a 50%
devaluation of the CFA, the currency of nine African countries that are former
colonies of France. The result was an immediate 100% increase in the price of
all imports in the local currency and, since all these countries are heavily
dependent on imports, a huge increase in overall prices. In consequence, real wages fell by nearly
40%.
In Mexico in the early 1980's and
again in 1995, a rapid devaluation of the peso, again under IMF plans, and
following huge capital flights by international investors, had the same
results: prices soared and real wages
dropped by nearly 50%. Here direct repression of workers struggles through a
corrupt union leadership restricted wage increases far below inflation. Often governments dictate real wage
decreases directly, as in Brazil in 1983, in another IMF enforced plan, where
wages were indexed at 80% of the inflation rate, resulting in real wage losses
equal to 20% of inflation.
But, in any case, sudden
devaluations immediately cut wages, so that any union struggle is an attempt to
regain old levels and thus inherently tends to lead to sharp real wage
losses. The same scenario was played
out dramatically in Eastern Europe in 1990 and the former Soviet Union in 1992,
when the fall of the Communist regimes was accompanied by IMF proposed massive
devaluation of currency, in the case of Russia, by some 200-fold. (As will be
detailed in the section on the former Soviet Union a massive theft of state
financial resources, including gold, was part of the cause of the size of the
devaluation). This instantly produced a mass of highly skilled workers
receiving wages a fraction of those in the West. In early 1992, wages in Russia averaged $10 a month and citizens
were hired by Western firms for $20 a month, less than 1% of the pay received
by their colleagues in the United States or Western Europe. At the same time massive inflation reduced
real wages by half. Here, the inflation
was not driven by imports, but by a bidding upwards of goods that were
enormously cheaper than the world
market price. Even in 1995, after huge inflation, average wages remained around
$100 a month. Naturally, this massive inflation also made worthless workers'
considerable savings in these countries, further reducing their total buying
power and eliminating reserves that could be relied on for strikes.
Devaluations are not the only means
of lowering pay in countries outside the developed capitalist core. While it is often difficult to use foreign
competition as a way to lower wages in countries with already low pay, within
any country there is inevitably a pay differential. By cutting the minimum wage, all wages can be ratcheted downwards
from internal competition among workers.
Thus in Bangladesh, the IMF insisted on a cut in the minimum wage from
$23 to $20 a month, which the Bangladesh government enforced, over the mass
protests of unionists there.[27]
More ominously, there is an
increasing recourse to forced, unpaid labor, a reinstitution of slavery, as the
ultimate competition with wage labor, and the way to force down even the lowest
pay rates. Of course, such forced labor
is not directly encouraged by IMF adjustment policies. But it is the unrelenting pressure to
increase exports and to cheapen the cost of production of such exports that
makes government wink at or even encourage such practices. In many countries of
Southern Asia, most notably Pakistan, this has taken the form of forced child
labor, in which children are sold by impoverished and debt ridden peasants to
rug factories or other plants. There, the children, sometimes shackled, work
without pay until a certain age.
Alternatively there is increasing use of prisoners as slave labor. China is most notorious for this practice,
although it is not limited to that country, by any means. In both cases, not only is the cost of labor
reduced to a bare minimum, but competition with free labor forces their wages
down. In both cases, the traditional
high security costs of slavery are avoided -- in the case of child labor,
because children do not need much force to enslave them, and in the case of
prisoners because the costs are absorbed by the state. (We will return to the serious issue of
forced labor in the chapter on the Third World.)
For the largest fraction of the
population that are peasants, not workers, austerity policies generally means
higher direct taxation. Under IMF
Structural Adjustment policies, government deficits are reduced not only by
reducing spending on social services, but by increasing taxes on the peasantry. In most countries, this generates a
continuous stream of impoverished peasants leaving their farms and moving to
the cities to seek work. High resulting
levels of unemployment, typically around 30-50%, again create competition and
depress wages. Finally, of course, all
these policies in non-developed countries are made easier by open
repression. In Bangladesh, for example,
when a general strike in 1994 protested IMF imposed austerity, there were mass
arrests of union leaders. In Bolivia,
in 1995, a general strike against privatizations and austerity policies was
answered by the imposition of a state of siege, outlawing of all public
meetings and the arrests of 10,000 union officials. In Mexico, government
repression is routinely used against leaders of independent unions.
The attacks on wages in the poorest
countries (and those newly poor, like the former Soviet Union) are essential to
the overall strategy of austerity. Why
do these wages, already so low in comparison with those of the advanced
countries, have to be reduced still further?
The answer is that, in a global economy, capitalism tends to equalize
the cost of labor in a given product.
Much higher wages in the advanced countries are compensated by much
higher levels of productivity, which cuts the cost of labor per item produced
to levels comparable with those in much lower wage areas. This is a reflection of the much higher
levels of education, and the accompanying much higher levels of mechanization
such education allows. To produce a
real competitive drain on wages in the advanced countries, where the vast
majority of labor costs are located, it is essential for capital to push
already depressed Third World wages still lower.
Simply reducing wages in some
countries would do capital no good globally unless the barriers that prevent
competition among the world's workers are at the same time broken down. This is
the primary motivation for the spate of free-trade treaties -- NAFTA in North
America, GATT for the whole world. By eliminating or decreasing tariffs, these
treaties have made it far easier to shift factories to the lowest wage areas,
in order to supply markets within the advanced countries. These shifts, in themselves, radically
reduce wage costs, and the threat of such shifts is used relentlessly to batter
down advance country wages. Thus, in
the wake of the collapse of wages in Poland, General Motors purchased a
recently privatized auto factory there and began producing GM cars there for
export to West Europe, paying wages starting at $1 an hour.[28] At the same time, GM closed plants in the US
and West Europe, where wages were typically $20 an hour. In Mexico, following the devaluation of the
peso in early 1995, and the passage of the NAFTA treaty, US manufacturers
shifted production in a wide variety of industries from the US and Canada to
Mexico, causing the loss of 150,000 jobs.[29] The huge shift in production of consumer
goods to China is obvious to anyone going into an American store, where even
the baseballs are made in China. In
some cases, factories are literally moved.
A massive steel plant built in 1979 in Fontana, California, in 1994 was
cut apart into 200-ton pieces and shipped to Beijing, China.[30]
This, then, is the
"international competition" that we have heard so much about,
especially when employers are trying to cut wages. The combination of massive austerity in the developing countries
with trade liberalization has led to a shift of work from high to low wage
areas, frequently with the same company being at both ends of the shift. The "foreign competition" for GM-USA
is often GM Poland, and the competition is purely among workers, not
corporations. The impact of these
globally driven shifts on the advanced countries is obvious. On the one hand, the loss of manufacturing
jobs increases unemployment and increases domestic competition among workers
for the remaining jobs. In the US, for
example, a shift of more than $100 billion dollars a year in the trade deficit,
has directly accounted for the loss of over three million jobs, and nearly half
of the 1995 unemployment.[31] Such increases in unemployment weakened the
ability of trade unions to fight wage cuts and speed-up in the advanced
countries. At the same time, the threat
of "foreign competition" and of "moving to Mexico -- or
China" is used directly as a threat to enforce acceptance of austerity in
the US, Europe and Japan. This global
whipsawing has established the most direct possible links between the interests
of workers in the advanced and undeveloped countries, links in interest that
workers are beginning to act on to fight such austerity, as we'll see in later
chapters.
imposing
austerity on the industrial countries
Generating competition among workers
and breaking working class solidarity both domestically and internationally, is
crucial to achieving austerity in the advanced countries, since the tools used
in the developing countries -- planned inflation and open repression -- are of
limited use in the industrialized states.
The obstacles in the way of open repression, established by decades of
struggle by working people, make its widespread use against workers impossible
at the present time, although anti-labor laws are beginning to be reintroduced,
most notably in Great Britain. And the
deliberate fostering of inflation to slashing real labor costs is a two-edged
sword in the developed countries. On
the one hand, the rapid inflation set off by the massive and deliberate oil
price increases of the seventies and
early eighties were, in fact, used to rapidly slash real wages in the advanced
countries. But at the same time, such
inflation cut as well the real value of capital, which is measured in terms of
the dollars, marks and yen. For this
reason, central banks much prefer, in
general ,to minimize inflation in the industrialized nations.
This leaves competition among
workers as the main way of imposing austerity.
Here the role of national governments is crucial for it's primarily
these governments that can break down the institutional barriers that have been
built up to hold back such competition among workers, barriers gained in
previous struggles. Equally, it has
been primarily organized labor that has determined how fiercely the collapse of
such barriers are fought. In countries,
particularly the United States, where an aggressive national government has met
with weak and ineffective opposition from unions, losses in standards of living
have been sweeping. While in countries
where stronger unions have put up more resistance, as in Germany, the losses have
been more limited.
In the US, the Federal government
has done much to generate competition among workers. Unemployment does not directly weaken unions unless scabs are
willing to cross picket lines and companies stay open in the face of strikes.
In the US, this had not happened from the 30's until the Reagan administration
in 1981 led the way by breaking the air controllers strike with civilian and
military scabs. That example, combined
with the shift in Federal policy to allow firing strikers, in defiance of
Federal law (the so-called permanent replacements of strikers -- a subtle
distinction from firing) allowed corporations to play off unemployed and
underemployed workers against strikers.
At the same time, the government
eroded the minimum floor of support for workers' incomes .
Republican and Democratic administrations alike held the minimum wage in
the US fixed as inflation reduced its
value by nearly 40%, and as unemployment benefits were cut and eligibility for
unemployment tightened. In addition,
welfare payments, the ultimate floor on workers' incomes, were also cut. The result was the production of a large
body of desperate workers, willing to cross picket lines for any chance at even
minimal pay. The threat of
"permanent replacements" with such desperate scabs was widely acknowledged
to be the primary reason for the enormous fall off in strikes in the US in the
past twenty years, and the ability of employers to force cuts in real wages and
working conditions.
In addition, existing labor-law
enforcement effectively ceased in many areas.
In New York City for example, but not there alone, flagrantly illegal
sweatshops paying far below the minimum wage -- as low as a dollar an hour --
illegally employing child labor have flourished under the noses of enforcement
agencies. In California, illegal
immigrants were held in slavery in such sweatshops. Again, not only does this
directly reduce wages for employers of this sweated or even forced labor, it produced competition that pulls down all
wages.
In the US, unions have in general,
been ineffective in combating these
radical shifts in government policy and, in fact, have until recently rarely
fought them at all, in part because of
the union leaders' close ties to the Democratic Party. Indeed, many unions have repeatedly yielded
to company demands for wage and benefit concessions, and even allowed internal
whipsawing of individual factories against each other, as in the auto
industry. The direct result has been an
erosion of real wages in the US by 20%.
In addition, without organized opposition, US corporations have
been able to reduce their workforces, substantially, imposing speed up and
longer hours on the remaining workers, again because of the threat of
replacement with unemployed workers.
The continuous drum beat of downsizing and layoffs, even by companies
who are maintaining production and not investing in automation, has resulted in
a nearly 10% increase in working hours in the US and almost universal speed up
during those hours. Naturally, the
increased unemployment caused by such speed up and longer hours has increased
the competition for jobs.
But where such austerity measures
have been resisted through worker solidarity, losses in workers' living
standards have been slowed. In France,
mass protests by students and workers in '94 prevented the imposition of a "youth minimum wage" which would
have allowed payment to those under wages 40% below the existing minimum. The massive strikes in '95, referred to at
the start of Chapter 1 rolled back Government assaults on pensions. In Germany,
where the unemployment rate in 1994-95 hovered around 10%, German metallurgical
unions first supported their east German members in a strike that preserved
rapid wage gains aimed at erasing the gap between eastern and western German
wages. Then, in 1995, another strike
forced corporations to stick to a pledge to reduce hours of work to 35 per
week.
But the ability to resist austerity
policies is not limited to Europeans.
In late 1994 and 95, US auto workers at a series of parts plants
suffering from 50-60 hour weeks successfully struck, demanding, for the first
time, not higher wages but the hiring of more workers to reduce unemployment
roles and cut working hours. Only a few
thousand jobs resulted from these strikes, but they were indications that the
rise in unemployment and speedup was not an inevitable process.
To be sure, even in countries where
unions remain strong, the global whipsawing laws allows capital to impose
significant austerity. In Germany, for
example, the transfer of significant manufacturing capacity to lower wages
areas --including the United States south -- has led to an unemployment rate
above 9% and a concomitant cut in overall income, despite substantial
unemployment benefits.
The role of national and local governments in imposing austerity is
not limited to methods that reduce direct wages and incomes. Of nearly equal importance have been the global and sweeping cuts in the
government provisions of essential services in health and education, cuts that have
been generally accompanied by cuts in taxes on the wealthy and on
businesses. In New York City,
headquarters of world capital, cuts in the funding of public hospitals, have
led to sharp increases in infant mortality rates, with a normal weight baby born
in public hospitals having a two thirds higher risk of death than one born in
the cities' private hospitals.[32]
In the Third World, IMF imposed budget cuts have reduced the share of GNP
devoted to health and education by over 12%, at a time when national wealth as
a whole is declining.[33] In Russia, where IMF imposed austerity has
been most devastating, health expenditures fell from 3% under the Soviet regime
to just 0.3% in 1995, with catastrophic results in rising death rates and
falling life expectancy.[34] Nor have educational systems been
spared. In California, the public
university system, once the best funded in the nation, expenditures have been
slashed and tuition in the university system greatly increased.
Finally, national governments use
shifts in taxation to further erode workers' incomes. In the United States, for example, Social Security taxes have
risen on workers earning less than $50,000 a year, while taxes have been
drastically cut, from 80 to 35%, for those earning over $200,000 a year. Fees
for previously free services, especially public education, have multiplied,
imposing a hidden taxation. And a
greater burden has been put on inherently regressive forms of taxation such as
sales taxes and value added taxes, which fall most heavily on working people.
Thus the imposition of austerity
relies heavily on the cooperation of national governments and the IMF. Without the global whipsawing, destruction
of labor guarantees, internal erosion of wage minimums and welfare, budget cuts
and tax shifts, it would be impossible for the corporations alone to carry out
such austerity policies.
PREVENTING DEFLATION:
RESTRUCTURING AND DESTROYING INDUSTRY
In the 1930's, austerity policies
that cut global consumption led to a devastating fall in commodity prices,
corporate and banking collapses as debts went unpaid, and an uncontrolled rise
in unemployment in the Great Depression. The Depression not only devastated
working people -- it caused the destruction of large sectors of capital as
well. Today, central bankers and
industrialists alike are well aware of the need to prevent a similar
deflation. The only way this can be
accomplished is by the planned
destruction of productive capacity in step with decreases in consumption. Since any individual corporation cutting
production would reduce its own market share, by its nature such
"restructuring" of industry has to be done at the international level
by agreements among governments or corporations in an entire industry. In essence, restructuring is the process of
creating global cartels to cut production.
Aluminum provides a simple example
of how the process works. First, a fall
in the demand for a specific commodity produces, or threatens to produce, a
collapse in prices. In the case of
aluminum, world aluminum demand fell precipitously from 1989 to 1992, for two
reasons. On the one hand, the recession
in the West and austerity measures there and in the Third World contracted
demand. On the other, the collapse of
the Eastern European and Soviet economies, brought about by the transition to
capitalism, and its accompanying soaring prices, almost eliminated their
internal demand for aluminum. But production did not fall nearly as much. Instead, Soviet, and then Russian, aluminum
plants started to export aluminum, produced at extremely low cost (due to
plummeting Russian wages) to the world market.
By 1993, Russian aluminum exports had increased six fold over '90
levels. As a result, world aluminum
prices dropped by nearly half.
Then came "restructuring". In February 1994, major aluminum producing
companies and representatives of the national governments of the US, Russia,
Canada, the European Union, Australia and Norway, the main producing countries,
met together to establish a producer's cartel.[35] Production quotas were agreed to for each
country, and it was agreed to reduce the overall level of production. But the heaviest cuts in production were
slated for the "highest cost" producers, that is the countries where
the wages were highest. Almost
immediately, American aluminum production was cut 10%, resulting in over ten
thousand layoffs. Russian production
boomed, with American and European aluminum producers sending bauxite ore mined
in their Third World mines to Russia for refining to aluminum, and then to
re-export for American and European industrial markets. As a result of the restructuring agreement,
aluminum prices stabilized. From the
standpoint of the producer, a deflation of prices was avoided, and profit
margins were actually boosted as production shifted to low wage regions. The results from the standpoint of the
American workers laid off was not as rosy.
To look at a much larger industry,
take steel. Steel production peaked in
the capitalist world in 1974 and has been stagnating since then. Again, there was a potential for major price
declines with the contraction of world industrial demand. But the European Union, and its predecessor
organization, the European Coal and Steel Community, stepped in to
"restructure" the industry -- closing factories to maintain
prices. Despite mass protests by
European steel unions, European programs have succeeded in reducing west
European steel production over the past 20 years by 25%. At the same time, production in Third World
countries has risen by 200% -- again shifting production from high wage to low
wage regions. In the US, restructuring
carried out by the steel companies themselves has reduced production during the
same period by almost 40%, turning formerly booming industrial regions like the
Mon Valley in Western Pennsylvania into virtual ghost towns.[36]
Such plant closings were not, it
must be emphasized, the inevitable consequences of contracting demand. Demand in a market economy exists relative
to a given price level. If prices had
been allowed to fall, demand would have been maintained and production would
have increased. But in such a case,
profit levels would not have been maintained -- for this
"restructuring", generally under governmental or international
controls, was essential. And, as with
austerity policies, effective resistance is possible. In Germany, where strong steel unions mobilized repeatedly
against mill closings, in 20 years production losses have been limited to 14%,
while in the United Kingdom, where union resistance was far weaker, production
fell in the same period by 50%, despite British wages being considerably lower
than German ones.[37]
PRIVATIZATION
While austerity and restructuring
are described by supporters of these policies as unfortunate necessities,
privatization is touted as a glorious economic step forward, liberating
economies from inefficient government bureaucracies. In the past decade, privatization, universally urged by the IMF,
has been applied by just about every government in the world. Throughout the globe, public sectors have
shriveled with privatizations ranging from core governmental services in the US
such as postal sorting or day care centers for state employees to
telecommunications in West Europe to the entire manufacturing sector in Russia.
There is no doubt that the massive
wave of privatization has brought huge new profits to capital, but to working
people it has been an unmitigated disaster, for exactly the same causes that
have made it a boon to capital. First
of all, privatization paves the way for restructuring and austerity --
privatizations of factories and services universally means reduction in
production, employment, wages and services provided. It is politically extremely difficult for governments to directly
shut down productive plants -- it too rapidly becomes an immediate political
issue. But if plants are privatized and
then shut down, the political opposition is dispersed and weakened. This is exactly what happened, for example,
in the former East Germany. After
unification in 1990 and the privatization of virtually all of the formerly
state owned industry, the East German auto industry was entirely shut down,
steel and cement were decimated, the highly advanced machine tool industry
eliminated. In just two years following
the mass privatizations, East German manufacturing output had shrunk by a
fantastic two thirds. The elimination
of jobs was similarly vast -- more than 40% of East German workers permanently
lost their jobs and became unemployed in 1990-92.[38] In many areas the only jobs remaining today
are in demolishing the closed factories.
In Russia, the later wave of privatizations in 1993-94 led to an equal
wave of plant closings and slashes in production, with total output falling by
50%.
Nor is this phenomenon of mass plant
closings limited to the former East Bloc.
In Bangladesh, the battle over the privatization of the jute plants,
referred to earlier, is particularly intense since the plan openly calls for
the closing of nearly all the plants once they are privatized.
The consequences of labor in mass
unemployment and the collapse of production are clear, but so are the benefits
for capital. Why shut down previously
productive enterprises? As in any
restructuring part of the motivation is a controlled decline of production to
maintain prices in a market shrunken by global austerity. But by shutting down previously state owned
enterprises, new capitalist owners can protect their own profitable production
while reducing global capacity at the same time. In general, the sale prices of privatized industries are so
trivial in relation to their actual value that the "investment" in
plants that will never produce again, is easily regained in higher prices
maintained elsewhere. At the same time,
the massive shut downs of state owned industries expands the market available
to existing capitalist production. Thus
in East Germany, as Eastern auto plants were shut, imports of Western made cars
increased. In Russia, entire cities
whose main product was domestic made clothing have ceased production, while
Moscow stores are filled with "western" imported clothing, generally
made in low wage areas such as South Asia.
Privatization also eases the imposition of austerity. On the one hand, privatization of public
services universally leads to cutting the amount of service available. The most extreme example of this is in
Russia, where the mass privatization of health services has led to cutting the
total expenditures on health by ten-fold, with catastrophic consequences for
life expectancy. At the same time,
privatization nearly always involves cuts in wages and staff. In the United States Post Office, for
example, unionized sorters paid $10 or more an hour have been replaced with
privatized contractors, usually located in the South that pay $5 an hour.[39] In New Jersey, state employed day care
workers earning $26,000 a year are to be replaced with private child care
providers paid $16,000 a year, and staffing levels are to be cut.[40] And, of course, in the former East Bloc,
privatizations have been accompanied by massive cuts in pay, generally around
50% in real terms.
In addition to reinforcing austerity
and restructuring privatization in itself represents a transfer of wealth from
labor to capital. Where plants and
services are maintained in being, revenue that previously flowed to the state
and was available for essential services is diverted to private profit. In cases where the state still funds the
services, the cost to the state often increases rather than decreases with
privatization. And, for the most part, privatizations occur at little or no
cost to the capitalist investors. In
Mexico, and in many other Latin American countries, in the 1980's, privatizations
of major state run enterprises, such as the Mexican telephone system, came in
"debt for equity" swaps, in which creditors of the Mexican state
redeemed debt for shared in privatized sectors. In Russia, industries were "sold" to managers for less
than 1% of their market value. These
vast thefts of wealth, linked to austerity which lowers the wages of workers in
these industries, represents huge shifts in the division of income between
workers and owners.
THE IDEOLOGICAL OFFENSIVE
The policies of the global assault
on labor are being accompanied by a propaganda offensive that seeks to justify
these policies and to weaken workers' resistance to them. This propaganda tries
to cover up the actual motivation for the assault and make it appear that
cooperation with austerity, restructuring and privatization is in the interests
of workers themselves. Clearly it won't
do for those implementing the policies to say, "we want to transfer large
amounts of wealth from labor to capital, from billions of workers and peasants
to a few thousand big capitalists and a few million small and medium
capitalists. Please help us to do this"
Such frankness will scarcely be rewarded with political support. Instead, advocates of the policies of the
assault use four main arguments to try to win labor support and broad political
acquiescence.
The first argument is that of
"free market efficiency" --that the policies, while perhaps painful
in the short run, in the long run will bring a higher standard of living, lower
unemployment, and real economic growth -- in short that the policies will
really benefit everyone, not just capital.
The second is the need for labor-management cooperation. In today's highly competitive global economy
goes this argument, labor must help corporations compete and be profitable, and
thus preserve the jobs the workers depended on. The third, and perhaps most dangerous argument is the appeal to
nationalism in all its forms. As in the
Great Depression, in a contracting world economy, the nationalist argument
urges each national or ethnic group to compete against the others, cutting for
themselves the biggest piece of a shrinking pie. This ranges from the need for
workers to support their corporations in their rivalry with foreign firms, to
anti-immigrant measures, to the fomenting of ethnic warfare and the re-growth
of fascistic movements. Finally,
advocates of the policies of the assault contend that there simply is no
alternative -- there is no better economic policy possible.
Let's look at these arguments in
turn. The most ubiquitous is the
"gospel of the market". In a
nutshell, it goes something like this:
"The world economic system is in trouble because there are too many
obstacles in the way of business efficiency and the investment that leads to
more jobs and growth. Consumption must
be cut so there will be more money going into investment. Corporations must cut back jobs, wages and
benefits now, so that they can compete more efficiently, become more
profitable, leading to growth in the future.
Privatization of government enterprises will improve efficiency and cut
waste, again leading to growth. In
short, we have to tighten our belts now temporarily, become lean and mean, and
thus pave the way for economic growth in the future, which will eventually lead
to a higher standard of living for all."
We can look at this argument in two ways -- first, can it possibly be
right, even in theory? And second, is
it right in actual practice, that is, do these policies accomplish what this
argument says they should?
In general, the free market arguments don't make any sense, if they are
looked at even cursorily. If consumption is cut in every country around the
world, as the IMF and other capitalist institutions urge, if wages and benefits
are reduced, then inevitably production must fall as well, shrinking the world
market still further, thus increasing unemployment, not increasing growth. While money taken from workers' wages does
increase corporate profits, such profits cannot go into funding new factories,
if the market is contracting. No
capitalist in their right mind is going to build new factories if they don't
have enough orders to keep existing factories running. Instead, profits flow inevitably into market
speculation, a pure chase of paper profits that create no new jobs, except for
Wall Street manipulators. Similarly,
for individual companies, who cut wages and lay off workers to "become
more competitive", no competitive advantage is gained, since all other
companies around the world are doing exactly the same thing. However, again, the market for goods
contracts, enforcing new rounds of layoffs. Even in theory, austerity and
restructuring lead to more austerity and restructuring. "We're firing you
to preserve jobs" makes just as much sense as it seems to.
It does, however lead to higher
profits, even as the market and production shrinks-- in the mid-90's stock
markets are at historic high levels, in
real-dollar terms, while living standards and employment shrivel -- indeed
stock prices rise with every announcement of mass layoffs, in anticipation of
increased profits. Individual companies don't gain competitive advantages, but
all companies make more profits as wage costs decline. Austerity and
restructuring thus make perfect sense for capitalists ,but not for workers,even
in theory.
In practice, the results are exactly
the same. The IMF has imposed
Structural Adjustment Programs on dozens of poorer countries around the world,
arguing that short term pain and austerity would lead to long term gain and
growth. In 1986, the IMF began
structural adjustment programs in eight mainly African countries. How did these programs work? In the poorer nations, per capita food
intake, as measured in calories per day, is a crude, but reliable, measure of
real wage and consumption levels. For
the IMF's "Class of '86" we can compare consumption levels in 84-86
with those two to four years after the start of the program, in 1988-90. FAO figures[41]
show that the result of the IMF programs was in almost all cases a sharp fall
in already dismal levels of consumption.
In this period of IMF structural adjustment, food consumption fell by 5%
in Bolivia, 15% in Burundi, 3% in Gambia, 5% in Niger, 1% in Senegal and 8% in
Sri Lanka. Only in Haiti and Mauritania
did food supply levels increase slightly.
In those countries where food production per capita figures are
available through 1992, the destruction by the IMF-approved policies continues
unabated. By 1992, per capita food production had fallen in Burundi by 5%, in
Gambia by 15%, in Haiti by 16% (prior to a 1992 collapse of another 22%), in
Mauritania by 10%, in Senegal by 19%.
If we use conventional measures of GNP per capita, the results are much
the same. In the decade of the 1980's
GNP per capita fell in Niger by 36%, in Mauritania by 12%, in Madagascar by
24%, in Bolivia by 20%. In two
countries, Uganda and Ghana, conditions declined so rapidly that the death
rates for children under 5, which generally are dropping in developing
countries, actually rose by 2 and 8% respectively.[42] In these two countries nearly a fifth of all
children born do not survive to their fifth birthday. Thus, over a six year period, the medium term results of IMF
austerity and restructuring is further sharp declines in the standard of
living.
To take another example, that of
Mexico, the IMF praised Mexico consistently during the 1980's and 90's for
carrying through profound reforms to privatize industry, cut domestic
consumption and increase exports, while opening up the country to imports. The IMF-approved plans led to dramatic falls
in real wages during the early and mid 1980's, which were only partially
recouped in the past few years. Yet
now, after following the IMF prescriptions, Mexico is again in a deep financial
crisis, and, with IMF advice, has imposed yet another round of sharp austerity
on its own people. The pro-government
union federation, the CTM, found that the real value of the minimum wage in
1995, following this latest round of austerity, was only one third of what it had been at its peak in 1976, and that average
real incomes are at their lowest levels since 1935. Unemployment is over 11% with another 16% underemployed at less
than the official minimum wage.[43]
What of the long term results? IMF spokesmen point to Chile as an example
of free market success. Chile is indeed
an excellent example of the results of IMF policies. In 1974, following the bloody Pinochet military coup, the first
of a series of IMF plans was agreed to by the Chilean dictatorship. These plans were renewed in 1983 and from
1985 to 1989 a medium-term IMF plan was in effect. The result has been a steady erosion of Chilean living
standards. In 1972, under the Allende
government, the FAO reported the average Chilean consumed 2807 calories per
day, not far below the contemporary level in Japan. In 1980, after six years of IMF policies, the food supply had
dropped by 6%. By 1985, it had dropped
by 8% and by 1989 by 11% to 2484. In 20
years, Chilean food supplies had fallen from the level of Japan to the level of
Mauritania.[44]
Since Chile is a semi-industrialized country, where workers will economize in
many ways before reducing their food intake, these figures greatly understate
the real decline in living standards.
But they show that after 20 years of IMF rule, there is no end to the
austerity. Unsurprsingly, policies aimed at reducing domestic consumption do
just that--permanently, or at least as long as the polices are adhered to.
The variant of the free market,
"austerity is good for you" argument used in the advanced countries,
contends that high wages are the cause of unemployment and that reducing wages
creates jobs. Again, the idea that
reducing wages, and thus overall consumption, can create jobs, when the demands
for goods is contracting, is a strange one.
But in any case, it is clear that it doesn't work. Among nations today, high unemployment and
low wages often go together, as in Spain, which has the lowest wages in Western
Europe, and an unemployment rate of 25%.
Japan, with its overvalued currency, now has the highest wages in the
world, and yet has an unemployment rate of little more than 3%.( Japanese
unemployment figures are understated but even realistic figures give Japan
among the lowest rates in the world)..
For a given nation low wage policies
don't reduce unemployment either. In
the United States, real wages have dropped by 20% and real minimum wages by a
whopping 37%, yet unemployment is higher, not lower, today than in 1973,
especially when involuntary part time work is taken into account.
The drumbeat of propaganda for
privatization is even louder than that for austerity -- privatization brings
the wonders of market efficiency to dinosaur-like public factories and
services. Again, even on the surface,
this argument makes little sense. Shifting
a service or product from public, non-profit to private for-profit status
inevitably means that somewhere a profit must be generated. This can come only by increasing the price
of the service or product or by decreasing the wages of those who provide it --
in order to channel some to the capitalists, who alone benefit from
privatization.
But we need not discuss theory,
since the market transformations of the former Soviet bloc countries provides a
colossal experiment in the effects of privatization. By any objective measure, not only has privatization led to
catastrophe in these countries, but the further privatization of industry and
essential social services has gone, the greater the extent of the
catastrophe. By nearly every measure,
every country is worse off today than under even the corrupt and ineffective
rule of the Stalinist bureaucracies, hardly a model of public
administration. Those countries who
have privatized the least, such as Slovakia, where nearly all essential
services and large-scale industry are still public and the Czech Republic and
Poland, where most industry and services are public, have suffered far less
than Russia, where there has been nearly complete privatization of industry and
such essential services as health.
What are the "benefits of
privatization" in practice? To be
sure, a few thousand ex-Communist bureaucrats have become fantastically wealthy
as the owners of privatized factories.
Foreign multinationals have found new sources of profit by buying for a
song privatized factories with their low-wage work force. But the impact on workers has been less
favorable. First, real wages have plummeted, dropping from 22% in Slovakia, 28%
in Poland, and more than 50% in Russia.
Even if real wages were to immediately and miraculously begin rising at as fast as 2% per year, the wage
level of the Soviet period would not be regained for 20 years in Poland and 40
years in Russia. In Russia the collapse
of minimum wages has been even more severe, their real value falling by an
incredible 80%, or a five-fold reduction. Unemployment has soared, reaching
nearly 45% in former East Germany, and 12-15% in the rest of East Europe,
excepting only the Czech republic.
Industrial production has plummeted, dropping by 70% in East Germany,
where privatization is complete, 45% in Russia, 33% in Poland. While the cheerleaders of privatizing
contend that the East Bloc was producing nothing that people wanted to buy, and
that shortages make money worthless anyway, the consumption of such basic
necessities as food has, in fact, withered away under the market reforms. Meat consumption, for example, has dropped
by 9% in Czechoslovakia and a massive 20% in Russia and 29% in Ukraine.[45] Evidently, meat is among the things
ex-socialist populations are glad to do without.
Of course, in the West, where production is mostly private,
privatization of social service is more the issue. Here, the record of the East is even grimmer. Throughout the region medicine production
and supply has been privatized, and in Russia, the entire public health
service, except for children, has been dismantled, while in East Europe, in
general, some form of public health funding has been maintained. Real public health spending in East Europe
has dropped by around 30% in Slovakia, the Czech republic, Poland and
Hungary. In Russia, it has fallen by
more than two thirds.[46]
The consequences of drastically
falling consumption, social service and unemployment on the population is
grim. Birth rates have plummeted, again
most severely in the most privatized countries. In the "least privatized" economies such as Slovakia,
the fall is only about 10%. But in
thoroughly privatized Russia, the drop in birth is 34%, and in Eastern Germany
the fall is a fantastic 70%. [47]
The typical "family size" there, if present trends continue, will be
.4 children per couple -- in other words, the typical German couple is not
having any children at all.
The reverse picture holds true of
death rates -- they are rising throughout the regions, but only slightly for
less privatized economies -- 5% for Slovakia -- and enormously for
much-privatized Russia, where the death rate has risen 50% since the collapse
of the Soviet Union. Among the benefits
of privatization in Russia is a fall of eight years in the life
expectancy. According to the United
Nations, there has never been a similar sharp fall in life expectancy in any
country during peacetime in recent history.[48] So, for falling wages, rising unemployment,
collapse in production, and a rapid expansion of grave-digging, privatization is clearly the prescription.
NATIONALISM -- THE OLDEST TACTIC
The use of nationalist, ethnic,
religious and racial prejudices to divide and weaken the working class is the
oldest and most used tactic of capital.
Today, nationalist rallying cries are particularly ironic at a time when
the entire global economy is integrated and the multinational corporations
themselves have freed themselves from any national boundaries or
allegiances. Unfortunately, despite its
age and absurdity, nationalism has not lost its effectiveness.
At its most pervasive level,
nationalist rhetoric is used to mobilize workers on behalf of corporations in
their, mostly fictional, struggle against the corporations and workers of other
countries. Thus, today, we see Chrysler
workers supporting ex-Chairman Lee Iococa in denouncing predatory Japanese auto
imports. The extent of the deception
involved here is evident when one considers that, for example, Chrysler is the
main shareholder in Mitsubishi and Peugeot, that 31% of Chrysler's cars are
made outside the United States, and that more broadly the majority of cars and
auto parts imported to the United States are made in factories either owned by
the US Big Three, or by companies in which they have a major shareholding
interest.[49] Workers are being drafted into a charade of
international competition as a way of aligning them with corporate interests,
and as a way to get them to compete with other workers around the world in
lowering their own wages and working conditions.
The broadbased campaign against the
North American Free Trade Treaty, unsuccessful though it was, provides a
glimpse of what an effective counter to such appeal to nationalist competition
can be. Many of the American and
Canadian unions participating in this campaign made contact with independent
unions in Mexico and jointly denounced the treaty as an attempt to reduce wages
and working conditions in all three countries.
Both before and after the treaty was approved, unions like the United
Electrical Workers, and individual locals within the United Auto Workers
actively collaborated with Mexican organizing drives and strikes, making the
point to their own members that the only way to fight "international
competition" was to raise the wages and working conditions of workers
everywhere in a joint fight against common multinational employers. As we'll see in later chapters, such moves
to establish international bargaining and international labor solidarity
actions are one of the key tasks before the global labor movement today.
A second, and generally more
vicious, form of this tactic is the fostering of anti-immigrant and racist
divisions within individual countries, a tactic that has been most prominent
recently within the United States and France.
Like the nationalist rhetoric about foreign competitions, the rhetoric
about illegal immigrants is enlisted to encourage a cutthroat competition among
workers. In this case, it is
competition for low paying jobs and services.
Large corporations, and the politicians who serve them, have no interest
in expelling illegal immigrants. On the
contrary, they want to make their life so difficult and precarious that they
will work for anything. In cities
across the US illegal immigrants are being exploited at wages far below the
minimum wage under sweatshop conditions and, in some cases, in actual
slavery. Initiatives such as
proposition 187 in California, which attempts to strip illegal aliens of their
rights to attend school and to receive emergency medical care, are intended, on
the one hand, to intimidate them further and make them more desperate for any
jobs. It is also intended to turn them
against legal residents, so that they can serve as strike breaking force.
Equally important, such campaigns are aimed at diverting the anger of legal
residents over deteriorating services against a portion of the working class,
the illegals, rather than against capital which is stripping essential services
of the financial resource needed to function.
In both the US and France, such
anti-immigrant campaigns are inevitably linked to racism (although in
California, support for Proposition 187 was also high among Hispanic
populations). As with the fascist
movements of the thirties, racist appeals can find a response within
chronically unemployed layers, shopkeepers, and professionals who have no
organizational links to the working class and whose desperation can be re-aimed
away from capital and towards other workers.
Fortunately, in general, the labor movement in both countries has begun
to mobilize against the anti-immigrant propaganda. In California, unions were not only active in the fight against
proposition 187, but have started to launch organizing drives that unite
illegal and legal immigrants and citizens, such as in the construction dates in
Southern California. We will look in
greater depth at the question of racism and immigrant backing in later
chapters.
The most extreme form of nationalism
is evident in the "ethnic" and religious warfare that has broken out
in various spots in the world, most notably in the former Yugoslavia. Contrary
to the impression circulated by most of the media, these conflicts have not
arisen out of centuries old simmering antagonism -- they have been quite consciously
and artificially been created. In
Yugoslavia, for example, following the collapse of the communist states, the
IMF had, with the cooperation of the Yugoslav leadership, imposed a program of
severe austerity. Yugoslav industry had
never been state owned, unlike the situation in other Eastern European
countries. Instead, plants are owned by
workers' collectives. However, the new policies were shifting the plants to
private ownership, reinforcing the already great powers of the plant
managers. At the same time, general
wage austerity was cutting the standards of living of Yugoslav workers. There was considerably opposition for the
workers, and, in the early 90's, there were widespread strikes. It was at this point that the Communist
bosses, such as Milosevic, began their sudden transformation into raving
nationalists, who advocated the breakup of Yugoslavia into its constituent
states such as Croatia, Slovenia and Bosnia.
None of these states were, in fact, ethnically based, but had more or
less arbitrary borders. In none of
these states were any democratic referendum held to approve the breakup --
indeed there was little popular support.
Nonetheless, by 1992 Croatia, Solvenia and Bosnia had broken away from
Serbia and Montenegro. But by itself,
this was not at all enough to ignite a murderous war.
For that, the Yugoslav government
selected some 20,000 criminals from its prisons, together with some
ex-convicts, provided as leadership a few psychopathic fascists and armed them
with hundreds of tanks, heavy artillery and tens of thousands of machine guns
from the well-equipped Yugoslav army.
It was this hardy band that then swept
into Croatia and then overran most of Bosnia. In an unarmed society of a few million, 20,000 criminals armed
with tanks and heavy guns can, unsurprisingly, do an enormous amount of
havoc. It was this deliberate act, not
some long-brooding antagonism, that initiated and sustained the bloody wars in
Croatia and Bosnia. In the process, of
course, the standard of living of the Yugoslav workers was reduced far below
the original austerity plans of the IMF, and resistance to such austerity
disappeared in the face of the mobilization of the Yugoslav oppositions for
war.[50]
IS THERE AN ALTERNATIVE?
The simplest argument used in defense
of the policies of austerity and restructuring is that there is no other
choice. As Murray Seeger, a spokesman for the IMF, said at a meeting in 1994
with trade union representatives, "The world is going through a structural
adjustment. There is no use for steel,
there is no use for jute. We say to
governments you have to adjust, you have to adapt, you have to
restructure. Things can't go on as they
do now."[51]
Like the other arguments for the
assault on labor, this one is false.
The myriad of human resources exists to greatly expand the standard of
living of workers and peasants through the world, to provide in a generation a
decent housing, clean water, good food, good education and good health services
for every human on Earth. But these
resources are currently either idle or wasted in non-productive pursuits like
the armaments industry. The financial
resources to mobilize these real resources exists as well, but they too are
wasted in a endless spiral of speculation and profit.
In the past few years, concrete
programs and plans of action have been discussed and are being adopted by labor
organizations. We will look at these
concrete proposals in later chapters.
But to understand what is the alternative to the assault, what can be
done, we must first look at why the assault is occurring. To cure a disease, we must know its
causes. So it is to the causes of the
assault on labor and the general economic crisis the world is enmeshed in that
we turn now.
CHART I
SOME TYPICAL LARGE CAPITALISTS[52]
John
Henry Bryan
Chmn,
CEO, Sara Lee Corp.
Director: Amoco, Catalysts, First Chicago Corp, First
National Bank of Chicago, General Motors
Phillip
M. Hawley
Director: AT&T, Atlantic Richfield, Bank of
America, Johnson and Johnson, Weyerhauser
William
R. Howell
Chmn,
CEO, J.C. Penney
Director: Bankers Trust, Exxon, Warner Lambert
Vernon
E. Jordan
Director: American Express, Bankers Trust, Corning,
Dow Jones, J.C. Penney, Revlon, RJR Nabisco, Ryder Systems, Sara Lee, Union
Carbide, Xerox
Charles
M. Pigott
Chmn,
CEO PACCAR
Director: Boeing, Chevron, Seattle Times
Charles
S. Sanford, Jr.
Chmn,
Bankers Trust
Director: J.C. Penney, Mobil Corp.
Frank
A. Shrontz
Chmn,
CEO Boeing
Director: Boise Cascade, Citicorp, MMM
John
G. Smale
Chmn,
CEO, Proctor and Gamble
Director: General Motors, J.P. Morgan, Morgan Guaranty
Trusts
George
H. Weyerhauser
Director: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
Boeing, Weyerhauser, Rand, Safeco
CHART II
INSTITUTIONAL OWNERSHIP OF VARIOUS
INDUSTRIES
(% OWNED BY OTHER CORPORATIONS AND
FINANCIAL INSTITUIONS)[53]
Aerospace 63
Airlines 51
Aluminum 60
Banking 54
Broadcasting 46
Chemicals 43
Computers 54
Electrical
Utilities 34
Electrical
Equipment 42
Electronic
defense 65
Food 44
Health 53
Insurance 53
Machine
Tools 69
Machinery 54
Oil 53
Publications 52
Rail 58
Savings
and Loans 52
Steel 52
Phone 30
Transportation
Equipment 51
CHART III
INSTITUTIONAL OWNERSHIP OF LEADING US
CORPORATIONS
(% OWNED BY OTHER CORPORATIONS AND
FINANCIAL INSTITUIONS)[54]
Banking
Citicorp 63
Bank
America 53
Chemical 68
Nations
Bank 56
J.P.
Morgan 60
Chase
Manhattan 62
Bankers
Trust 68
Banc
One 49
Wells
Fargo 64
PNC 53
First
Chicago 70
Northwest 66
Bank
of NY 66
Mellon 66
Aerospace
Boeing 49
United
Technologies 76
McDonnel
Douglas 53
Allied
Signal 69
Lockheed 96
General
Dynamics 56
Textron 66
Northrop 60
Grumman 36
Chemical
Dupont 42
Dow 56
Occidental 47
MMM 62
Wr
Grace 77
Union
Carbide 52
Computers
IBM 39
Hewlett
Packard 58
Digital 57
Unisys 44
Apple 46
Intel 71
Electronics
GE 54
Motorola 73
Westinghouse 36
Rockwell 34
Raythronics 71
ATT 30
ITT 71
Auto
GM 48
Ford 61
Chrysler 67
Metals
Alcoa 80
Reynolds 80
USX 66
LTV 71
Bethlehem 86
Oil
Exxon 40
Mobil 52
Chevron 44
Texaco 58
Amoco 57
Shell 29
Atlantic 60
Pharmaceuticals
Johnson
and Johnson 51
Bristol
Myers 45
Merck 45
Abott 40
Pfizer 60
Publishers
Time
Mirror 57
Knight
Ridder 63
McGraw
Hill 67
New
York Times 52
Scientific
Kodak 61
Xerox 85
Honeywell 63
Transportation
United 83
Delta 67
CSX 59
Federal
Express 79
CHART IV
OWNERSHIP OF SOME INDIVIDUAL COMPANIES[55]
United
Technologies -- 26 institutions own 48%
Top
Investors: Capital Research, Bernstein,
Fidelity, Neubold, Ivesco, Smith Barney, Bankers Trust, Wells Fargo, Miller
Boeing
-- 34 institutions own 31%
Top
Investors: Capital Guardian, Wells
Fargo, Ivesco, Bankers Trust, Capital Research, Franklin, Cooke, College
Retirement
Bankers
Trust -- 20 institutions hold 41%
Top
Investors: Capital Research,
Wellington, Barrow, Wells Fargo
Wells
Fargo -- 30 institutions own 48%
Top
Investors: Berkshire, Neubergers, Smith
Barney, Capital Research, wells Fargo
Chemical
-- 23 institutions hold 41%
Top
Investors: Barrow, Bernstein, Fidelity,
Capital Growth, Lazard Forces, Bankers Trust